首页
外语
计算机
考研
公务员
职业资格
财经
工程
司法
医学
专升本
自考
实用职业技能
登录
外语
A newspaper cannot publish for 174 years without some mistakes. This one has made its share. We thought Britain was safe in the
A newspaper cannot publish for 174 years without some mistakes. This one has made its share. We thought Britain was safe in the
admin
2018-01-01
44
问题
A newspaper cannot publish for 174 years without some mistakes. This one has made its share. We thought Britain was safe in the European exchange-rate mechanism just weeks before it crashed out; we noted in 1999 that $10 oil might reach $5; and in 2003 we supported the invasion of Iraq. For individuals, like publications, errors are painful—particularly now, when the digital evidence of failure is both accessible and indelible. But they are also inevitable. The trick is to err well: to recognise mistakes and learn from them. Worryingly, humanity may be getting worse at owning up to its goofs.
Few enjoy the feeling of being caught out in an error. But real trouble starts when the desire to avoid a reckoning leads to a refusal to grapple with contrary evidence. Economists often assume that people are rational. Yet years of economic research illuminate the ways in which human cognition veers from rationality. Studies confirm that people frequently disregard information that conflicts with their view of the world. Why should that be? Last year Roland Benabou and Jean Tirole presented a framework for thinking about the problem. In many ways, beliefs are like other goods. People spend time and resources building them, and derive value from them. Some beliefs are like consumption goods. Other beliefs provide value by shaping behaviour. The conviction that one is a good salesman may help generate the confidence needed to close sales.
Because beliefs are not simply tools for making good decisions, but are treasured in their own right, new information that challenges them is unwelcome. People often engage in "motivated reasoning" to manage such challenges. Mr. Benabou classifies this into three categories. "Strategic ignorance" is when a believer avoids information offering conflicting evidence. In "reality denial" troubling evidence is rationalised away: houseprice bulls might conjure up fanciful theories for why prices should behave unusually, and supporters of a disgraced politician might invent conspiracies. And lastly, in "self-signalling", the believer creates his own tools to interpret the facts in the way he wants; an unhealthy person might decide that going for a daily run proves he is well.
Motivated reasoning is a cognitive bias to which better-educated people are especially prone. Not all the errors it leads to are costly. But when biases are shared, danger lurks. Motivated reasoning helps explain why viewpoints polarise even as more information is more easily available than ever before. That it is easy to find convincing demolitions of climate-change myths, for example, has not curbed misinformation on the topic. But the demand for good (or bad) information is uneven. Polling shows, for example, that Democrats with high levels of scientific knowledge are more concerned about climate change than fellow partisans with less scientific background. Even, or especially, sophisticated news consumers look for what they want to find.
Work by Mr. Benabou suggests that groupthink is highest when people within groups face a shared fate: when choosing to break from a group is unlikely to spare an individual the costs of the group’s errors. If a politician’s fortunes rise and fall with his party’s, breaking from groupthink brings little individual benefit (but may impose costs). The incentive to engage in motivated reasoning is high as a result. Even as the facts on a particular issue converge in one direction, parties can still become polarised around belief-sets. That, in turn, can make it harder for a party member to derive any benefit from breaking ranks. Indeed, the group has an incentive to delegitimise independent voices. So the unanimity of views can be hard to escape until it contributes to a crisis.
Lowering the cost of admitting error could help defuse these crises. A new issue of Econ Journal Watch, an online journal, includes a symposium in which prominent economic thinkers are asked to provide their "most regretted statements". Held regularly, such exercises might take the shame out of changing your mind. Yet the symposium also shows how hard it is for scholars to grapple with intellectual regret. Some contributions are candid; Tyler Cowen’s analysis of how and why he underestimated the risk of financial crisis in 2007 is enlightening. But some disappoint, picking out regrets that cast the writer in a flattering light or using the opportunity to shift blame.
Public statements of regret are risky in a rigidly polarised world. Admissions of error both provide propaganda for ideological opponents and annoy fellow-travellers. Some economists used to seethe when members of the guild acknowledged that trade liberalisation could yield costs as well as benefits. In the long run, such self-censorship probably eroded trust in economists’ arguments more than it built support for trade. It is rarely in the interest of those in the right to pretend that they are never wrong.
What does Roland Benabou and Jean Tirole’s research tell us? What is "motivated reasoning" (para.4) ?
选项
答案
to study why people often "disregard information that conflicts with their view of the world" / why human cognition separated from rationality ("veers from rationality") / proposed a framework on the issue / people often rely more on "beliefs" built up by themselves and even derive values from such beliefs / for some people, beliefs have become "consumption goods" / used to make decisions / treasured by those people "in their own right"/ motivated reasoning divided into three categories: strategic ignorance, reality denial and self-signalling, / is a "cognitive bias" / people with better education are prone to such cognition / shared biases could lead to dangers + risks
解析
转载请注明原文地址:https://jikaoti.com/ti/u4CYFFFM
本试题收录于:
NAETI高级口译笔试题库外语翻译证书(NAETI)分类
0
NAETI高级口译笔试
外语翻译证书(NAETI)
相关试题推荐
随着中国实现总量控制的目标所面临的挑战日益严峻,以部门为基础分配减排责任的可能性越来越大。另外,根据最新修订的《空气清洁条例》,排放许可最终被赋予了法律地位,并在指定和执行减排义务中起指导性作用。//根据这两项最新的政策进展,美国环保协会已经和国家环保总局
A、20%.B、15%.C、10%.D、9%.C根据题干要求可从原文中找到全球旅游业和GDP(国内生产总值)之间的关系。原文第一句提到“Globaltourism...represents10percentofworldGDP...”,
A、Itisactuallyacucumber-shapedbuildinglocatedinBritain.B、Itisacucumber-shapedbuildinglocatedinSwitzerland.C、It
A、Indifferent.B、SurprisedC、Cooperative.D、Confused.A将相关重要单词或词组进行简单归纳。本题原文中讲话者表达观点时,使用了unmoved,cannotaffordtowastetime,non
A、shockB、ananticipationofphraseC、theoriginalityofthethoughtD、ingeniousnessB正确理解上下文中某些词语的指代关系是解题的关键。本题文中需正确理解thepleas
Peopleofdifferentfieldscametogetherforthesamedreamofbuildingasmartcity.
Peopleofdifferentfieldscametogetherforthesamedreamofbuildingasmartcity.
A、Topromotesalesofbicycles.B、Toencouragecycling.C、Toreducecaraccidents.D、Toimproveroadconditions.B
OnSaturdaymorningsIworkedinthefamilyshop.IstartedcyclingdowntotheshopwithDadonSaturdayassoonasIwasbige
OnSaturdaymorningsIworkedinthefamilyshop.IstartedcyclingdowntotheshopwithDadonSaturdayassoonasIwasbige
随机试题
课程的定义(我国教育学家提出的)是什么?
在PowerPoint2010中,下面________不是合法的“打印内容”选项。
A.入球小动脉平滑肌B.球外系膜细胞C.出球小动脉平滑肌细胞D.球旁细胞E.致密斑细胞肾感受Na+含量变化的细胞是
玻璃幕墙与主体结构的连接件应做好()处理。
下列关于可转换债券的表述中,正确的有()。
所谓高度集中的计划经济,是以市场手段为基础来配置社会资源的经济形式。()
2012年非金融领域新批外商直接投资企业24925家,比上年下降10.1%。实际使用外商直接投资金额1117亿美元,下降3.7%。2012年非金融类埘外直接投资额772亿美元,增长28.6%,比上年提高26.8个百分点。2012年对外承包工程业务完成营
The UNIX operating system is made up of three parts; the kernel, the shell and the programs. The kernel of UNIX is the(71)of the
人在世上都离不开朋友,但是,最忠实的朋友【131】自己,就看你是否善于做自己的朋友了。要能够做自己的朋友,你就【132】比外在的自己站得更高,看得更远,【133】才能够从人生的全景出发给他【134】提醒、鼓励和指导。事实【135】,在我们每个人身上,除了外
SomebusinessbooksarelikeaCDrecordedbyaone-hit-wonderpopstar.OntheCD,thestar’soriginalhitispaddedwithdross
最新回复
(
0
)