For the past 3,000 years, when people thought of money they thought of cash. From buying food to settling bar tabs, day-to-day d

admin2021-06-15  1

问题         For the past 3,000 years, when people thought of money they thought of cash. From buying food to settling bar tabs, day-to-day dealings involved creased paper or clinking bits of metal. Over the past decade, however, digital payments have taken off—tapping your plastic on a terminal or swiping a smartphone has become normal. Now this revolution is about to turn cash into an endangered species in some rich economies. That will make the economy more efficient—but it also poses new problems that could hold the transition hostage.
        Countries are eliminating cash at varying speeds. But the direction of travel is clear, and in some cases the journey is nearly complete. In Sweden the number of retail cash transactions per person has fallen by 80% in the past ten years. Cash accounts for just 6% of purchases by value in Norway. Britain is probably four or six years behind the Nordic countries. America is perhaps a decade behind. Outside the rich world, cash is still king. But even there its dominance is being eroded. In China digital payments rose from 4% of all payments in 2012 to 34% in 2017.
        Cash is dying out because of two forces. One is demand—younger consumers want payment systems that plug seamlessly into their digital lives. But equally important is that suppliers such as banks and tech firms (in developed markets) and telecoms companies (in emerging ones) are developing fast, easy-to-use payment technologies from which they can pull data and pocket fees. There is a high cost to running the infrastructure behind the cash economy—ATMs, vans carrying notes, tellers who accept coins. Most financial firms are keen to abandon it, or deter old-fashioned customers with hefty fees.
        In the main, the prospect of a cashless economy is excellent news. Cash is inefficient. In rich countries, minting, sorting, storing and distributing it is estimated to cost about 0. 5% of GDP. But that does not begin to capture the gains. When payments dematerialize, people and shops are less vulnerable to theft. Governments can keep closer tabs on fraud or tax evasion. Digitalisation vastly expands the playground of small businesses and sole traders by enabling them to sell beyond their borders. It also creates a credit history, helping consumers borrow.
        Yet set against these benefits are a bundle of worries Electronic payment systems may be vulnerable to technical failures, power blackouts and cyber-attacks—this week Capital One, an American bank, became the latest firm to be hacked. In a cashless economy the poor, the elderly and country folk may be left behind. And eradicating cash, an anonymous payment method, for a digital system could let governments snoop on people’s shopping habits and private titans exploit their personal data.
        These problems have three remedies. First, governments need to ensure that central banks’ monopoly over coins and notes is not replaced by private monopolies over digital money. Rather than letting a few credit-card firms have a stranglehold on the electronic pipes for digital payments, as America may yet allow, governments must ensure the payments plumbing is open to a range of digital firms which can build services on top of it. They should urge banks to offer cheap, instant, bank-to-bank digital transfers between deposit accounts, as in Sweden and the Netherlands. Competition should keep prices low so that the poor can afford most services, and it should also mean that if one firm stumbles others can step in, making the system resilient.
        Second, governments should maintain banks’ obligation to keep customer information private, so that the plumbing remains anonymous. Digital firms that use this plumbing to offer services should be free to monetise transaction data, through, for example, advertising, so long as their business model is made explicit to users. Some customers will favour free services that track their purchases; others will want to pay to be left alone.
        Last, the phase-out of cash should be gradual. For a period of ten years, banks should be obliged to accept and distribute cash in populated areas. This will buy governments time to help the poor open bank accounts, educate the elderly and beef up internet access in rural areas. The rush towards digital money is the result of spontaneous demand and innovation. To pocket all the rewards, governments need to prepare for the day when crumpled bank notes change hands for the last time.
Which of the following is NOT one of the advantages of cashless economy based on the article?

选项 A、Countries are hiring more tellers to accept coins for them.
B、Cashless economy vastly expands the playground of small businesses and sole traders by enabling them to sell beyond their borders.
C、Governments can keep closer tabs on fraud or tax evasion.
D、When payments dematerialise, people and shops are less vulnerable to theft.

答案A

解析 细节题。题干:根据文章,下列哪项不是无现金经济的优点?题干关键词为advantages,替换了第五段首句“Yet set against these benefits are a bundle of worries.(然而,与这些好处相对的是一堆烦恼)”中的benefits。根据第四段可知,当支付变得非物质化时,人们和商店就不那么容易遭受盗窃。政府可以密切监管欺诈和逃税行为。数字化极大地扩展了小企业和个体经营者的活动范围,使他们能够在境外销售产品。这还创造了信用记录,有助于消费者借贷。由此可知无现金经济的优点:一是防盗;二是防止逃税和欺诈;三是扩展了小企业和个体经营者的活动范围;四是创造信用记录,方便消费者借贷。B项“无现金经济极大地扩展了小企业和个体经营者的活动范围”对应了无现金经济的第三个优点,C项“政府可以密切监管欺诈和逃税行为”对应了无现金经济的第二个优点,D项“当支付变得非物质化时,人们和商店就不那么容易被盗”则对应了第一个优点。A项“各国要雇佣更多的出纳员为它们接收硬币”,根据第三段倒数第二句“There is a high cost to running the infrastructure behind the cash economy—ATMs,vans carrying notes,tellers who accept coins.(现金经济背后的基础运行设施即自动取款机、运钞车和接收硬币的出纳员成本很高)”可知,雇佣负责接收硬币的出纳员是运行现金经济的高额成本之一,由此可推断无现金经济对此类出纳员的需求会降低,A项错误。故本题选A。
转载请注明原文地址:https://jikaoti.com/ti/VW1QFFFM
0

最新回复(0)